Documentation

Informations sur la décision

Contenu de la décision

Attention : ce document est disponible en anglais seulement.

CT-94/01 THE COMPETITION TRIBUNAL IN THE MAT IER OF an Application by the Director of Investigation and Research under section 79 of the Competition Act R.S.C. 1985 c.C-34 as amended.

AND IN TiiE MAT IER OF certain practices by A.C. Nielsen Company of Canada Limited.

BETWEEN: THE DIRECTOR OF INVESTIGATION AND RESEARCH Applicant

-and-A.C. NIEISEN COMPANY OF CANADA LIMITED Respondent

-and-INFORMATION RESOURCES, INC. Intervenor

AFFIDAVIT OF PROFESSOR FRANK MATHEWSON (on behalf of the Respondent)

. ,, COMPETITiON TmSUNAL J TRIBUNAL OE LA CONCLRRENCE

File No. C, £. No.~ itossier I I\ - 94J~ · e' 6 . :;· c.q.) ~ _hLJ.,t,v I " ~ < 1 · et ' ( ) ~E1hibi1 Ho. - ·_f:: /o.{ ~ 8 7 No. de la ple~c /c,{ ·. .J~Z. filedon ~ ,;Jpl ' Oeposee le VA , ' Rogis._mr I ~u~~~~ ~...:-·- -Grether

;, ' .:,,,,;•

AFFIDAVIT OF PROFESSOR FRANK MATHEWSON I, Professor Frank Mathewson, in the City of Toronto, in the Province of Ontario, MAKE OATH AND SAY: 1 I hold an appointment as a Professor of Economics in the Department of Economics and as Research Associate in the Institute for Policy Analysis, both at the University of Toronto. My research and my university teaching is in applied microeconomics in general and the field of Industrial Organi7.ation in particular. For several years now, I have taught undergraduate and graduate courses in Industrial Organil.ation in the Department of Economics at the University of Toronto.

2 As a professional economist, I have been asked by Nielsen Marketing Research (Nielsei;i) and counsel to Nielsen to address the following issues:

2.1 the competitive nature of the market for market tracking services for retailers and manufacturers in Canada;

2.2 the competitive impact of the contracts between Nielsen and the suppliers of scanner data to Nielsen, including the competitive impact of the restrictions that prevent a supplier from making scanner data available to others.

2 3 My ability to comment on these issues is based on my experience and knowledge in the field of industrial organization and competition policy. I have also been provided with and have relied on information provided to me by Nielsen and its counsel.

4 Attached hereto as Exhibit "A" to this affidavit is a true copy of the report prepared for Nielsen pursuant to its request.

5 My academic training and my research record are set out in my curriculum vitae which appears in Appendix A to my report. A brief summary of my experience as an expert witness appears with my curriculum vitae in Appendix A.

Sworn before me at the ) City of Toronto in the ) Province of Ontario ) this 20th day of Sept.ember 1994. ) Professor Frank Mathewson ,...._..._ Gluteppena '"' ,. ..... a01 ma'11' •,Mc., Prov· 0 ......... a llUClenl,at-1 .... a JP ....... 1.7. l!i~

EXHmIT A EXPERT ECONOMIC EVIDENCE OF FRANK MATHEWSON IN THE MA'l*fER BETWEEN THE DIRECTOR OF INVFSTIGATION AND RESEARCH AND NIEUEN MARKETING RESEARCH

Frank Mathewson Imtltute for Polley Analysis and Department ol Ecoaomk:s University ol Toronto

140 St. Geolae Street Toronto Ontario M!S lAl

September 20, 1994

Table of Contents 1 Summary of Conclusions 2 Analysis 2.1 The Products 2.2 The Players in the Market (a) retailers (b) manufacturen 2.3 The Nature of the Product Market: Market Tracking Services 2.4 The Contracts in the Market (a) historical (b) prospective (c ) exclusivity (d ) financial inducements 2.5 Competitive Effects (a) length of contract (b) prices and services in Canada· (c) entry 3 Conclusions Appendix A: Curriculum Vitae

Pqe Number 3 4 7 8 10 11 14 15 17 19 20 21 22 24

1 Summary of Cooclusiom 1. l There are alternative sources of market tracking data available in Canada. 1. 2 Major retail grocery chains in Canada and many of the manufacturers who use market tracking services are large and capable of negotiating favourable terms in their contracts with suppliers of inputs such as Nielsen.

1.3 Since 1986, the contract negotiation process between the major retail grocery chains and Nielsen has been independent and sequential. This means that a firm such as IRI established in the US and other world markets could have chosen to bid on these contracts on any basis it saw fit, in accordance with each retailer's request. .• 1.4 I could find no evidence that Nielsen used financial inducements in an anticompetitive manner to induce the major retail groceiy store chains to use Nielsen as their exclusive agent for scanning data.

1.5 I could find no evidence that the length of the contract with each of the major retail grocery chains reflects other than conventional commercial principles when parties negotiate a contract.

1. 6 The evidence is that during the period 1986 to the present the real price of the Nielsen market tracking service was constant or declined marginally and the quality of the product increased as the scanning based data became more reliable and usable.

4 2 Analym 2.1 The Products 2.1.1 The market for market tracking services in Canada and elsewhere is governed by contracts between suppliers and demanders of these services. It is these contracts that are the focus of the competition issues in this case. The products in this market include both data on consumer purchases and analyses of these data. Data are collected from retailers and consumers by intermediaries such as Nielsen. The data are processedt repackaged, frequently analyzed, and then sold back to retailen and manufacturers in the form of reports and applications. Conditions of sale are set out in the retailer and manufacturing contracts. Market tracking services are used by these retailen and manufacturers to fo~ulate, implement, and monitor their marketing strategies.

2.1.2 For example, quantity and price data permit the user of the data to track the impact on demand of experimental price variation initiated through such devices as local promotions in place for specific time intervals. Put simply, data on consumer purchases under various conditions are collected from retail sources and then processed and sold to demanders, frequently with additional software products and applications, and consulting services (in total, decision support services). The retailers can be food and drug retailers as well as mass merchandisers. The latter are growing in importance in the retail sector in North America. The manufacturers are all of those distributing their products to the market through the relevant set of retail outlets.

5 2.1.3 The sources for the data include: (i) data taken from the point of sale (retail outlet) and provided by the retailer using scanning technology; (ii) data taken from store audits conducted by the intermediary; (iii) data taken from withdrawals from the retailer's warehouse; (iv) data taken from factory shipments; (v) data taken from consumer panels, set-up and maintained by the various intermediaries using diary data; (vi) data collected from consumer panels where consumers, set-up and maintained by the various intermediaries, using a portable scanner, scan their own purchases at home. There are two features of these data worthy of note.

2.1.4 The first is that users of these data need data compiled and aggregated along several lines. Sometimes highly disaggregated data are required~ for example, the impact of selective price reductions or in-store advertising and display initiatives on specific products or product cat.egories in specific locations. Sometimes the data needs are more aggregated such as the movement of product at specific prices within a given region or province or country-wide. Sometimes the data are aggregated by brand names or product categories for specific retail chains ('key account' data). This permits a manufacturer to track product flow through a particular retail chain. The point is that data sources and needs are diverse. This permits business opportunities at various levels (geographically or trade level specific) in this

6 industry both to collect data and to provide the decision support services that are demanded appropriate to the data at. hand.

2.1.5 The second feature relates to the nature of the data collection itself. In general, the more complete the sample size, the more reliable are the data: incomplete samples can lead to sampling error. 1 The trade-offs are in terms of the cost of increasing the sample sii.e against minimizing sampling error. This general principle is applicable to any geographical sample. For example, this principle has relevance to national data. Reliable national or aggregate data require a representative sample from the regions of the country. Otherwise ' by definition, the data cannot be national. Further discussion on this point appears below. .' 2.1.6 As I note above, these data do not speak for themselves but require additional decision support services which use the data as an input, utilizing and transforming the data to produce reports and evaluations relevant to marketing and price strategy for the end user. The identity of the firm producing the software products and applications and consulting services may be the same as the intermediary collecting and repackaging the data or it may be a different firm. Nothina prevents any end user from purchasing the data from one source and then usina another consultant as a marketing advisor to the firm. In general, any conuact govemina the purchase of any subset of data from the retailers may be the same or a different contract from that contract governing the additional services provided to the retailer

I This does nQl meall that regional samples are inferi~ to national samples. What it does mean is that within any geographical market, a larger sample will reduce sampling error.

7 by the data intermediary. Nielsen is one intermediary in Canada that provides both services: it collects particular marketing data and sells decision support services to both the retail and manufacturing sectors. Other intermediaries provide data from alternative sources and compete with Nielsen in providing decision support services. Even with Nielsen's current contracts with retailers, a firm such as Information Resources Inc. (IRI) could and does provide modelling and other analytic services to clients in both the retail and manufacturing sector.

2.2 The Players in the Market (a) retailers 2.2.1 The retail sector in Canada is characteriz.ed by a high degree of regional and even provincial specializ.ation. Within each of these regions, particular regional chains have a strong market presence. In 1985, when it was considering the acquisition of scanning data, Nielsen identified each of the important regional grocery distributors as follows:

For scanning data, Nielsen currendy has contracts with major retail grocery chains such as

8 2.2.2 This list reveals that the retail chains are large and have regional concentration. Provision of a national tracking service based on scanning data certainly is facilitated by having ready access to data collected from each of these large chains. An intermediary wishing to produce a national market tracking service would need data for each of the regions of Canada. These could be either collected by the intermediary or purchased from another intermediary. . 2.2.3. The regional concentration of these retail chains also reveals that these players are

unlikely to be contract takers on an individual basis. Terms of trade and other contractual conditions will actively reflect the wishes and desires of each retailer. If a retailer decides that it is desirable to have a single agent to process and market the data, then it is reasonable to expect single representation. On the other hand, if a retailer decides to sell to more than one intennediary, that too is each retailer's choice.

(b) JMnulacturen 2.2.4 While the list of Nielsen's canactian manufacturing clients reveals some variation in the siz.e of these firms, the largest of these firms are large international firms. For example, the top 10 customers (out of approximately food or grocery customers), listed in order of size of expenditures on Nielsen's mainline food tracking service are:

9

) These top 10 customers account for '6 of Nielsen• s gross revenues from its major customers for Nielsen's MarketTrack Grocery (food only) service.

2.2.5 These manufacturing firms operate internationally. It is reasonable to claim that they are sophisticated and knowledpable and have significant bargaining powa: in their relationships with their suppliers to secure inputs at minimum prices and on reasonable tenns. These inputs include those marketing services such as marketing data and various modelling and strategic services that use these data.

2.2.6 Such large finns are unlikely to be the recipient of any alleged anticompetitive

10 behaviour on the part of any supplier of inputs including those supplying national market tracking data and analysis. Individually or collectively, these manufacturers have bargaining power. For example, these manufacturers could cut back on their demand for Nielsen's services. They could withhold payment for services already used. They could purchase services from an alternative source of marketing tracking information such as ISL. The manufacturer's individual bargaining ability may be enhanced through common membership in the Grocery Products Manufacturers of Canada. For example, any threat from this collective of manufacturers to exercise a boycott of any potentially non-competitive provision of inputs such as national market tracking services and its applications would constitute r. considerable market discipline on the provision of these data and accompanying services. The potential for such action may alone be the market disciplining force.

2.2. 7 Another option open to these international manufacturers is to influence favourably the terms and conditions that they receive in Canada through the terms and conditions that they are accorded by Nielsen in other national markets. I understand from Nielsen personnel that such efforts actually occur during contract negotiation. As a consequence, the realimi competition, for example in Canada, is capable of reflecting the competitive conditions that prevail in other national markets such as the US.

2.3 The Nature of the Product Market: Market Tracldna Services 2.3.1 The product market (market tracking services) is large and diverse. As I indicate above, there are alternative sources of marketing data and analysis. The data required may

11 be local, regional, provincial or national. The data may be sourced from store scanning, store audits, warehouse sl)ipments, factory shipments, consumer diaries, and consumer scanning.

2. 3. 2 There is variation in the quality of these data based on the extent of coverage and reliability but no retailer or manufacturer is restricted to a single choice. For example, in the Canadian market, attributes of market tracking services vary according to the source of the data and the firm supplying the data.

2.3.3 Smaller manufacturers whose markets are provincial or regional may choose to use non-sCanning based marketing data and analysis. As such, they are unaffected by the contracts in force for collecting and processing national scanning data.

2.4 The Contncts in the Market (a) hntorical 2.4.1 The evidence is that in 1986, IRl initiated an exclusivity game with the major Canadian retailer chains by proposing to the major food retail chains in Canada that IR.I be the exclusive agent for assembling, processing and selling scanning data collected from the major Canadian grocery retailers. I understand that this initial IRI offer was on an 'all-or-nothing' basis to these major grocery store retail chains. As part of its contract, IRI would process the data, offer the processed packages to the individual food retailers that were specific to each chain and also act as the sole broker of these data, possibly selling other

12 marketing and decision support services to the appropriate manufacturers. While other food retailers had reached an agreement with IRI, Canada Safeway, Steinbergs, and loblaws did not. The claim is that as Canada Safeway represented a large percentage of retail grocery sales in Western Canada, Safeway's inclusion was important for a complete data set. Safeway's hold-out afforded an opportunity for Nielsen to respond with independent bids of its own to the contractual offen made by IRI.

2.4.2 Confronted with the fact that IRI had initiated a bidding game based on exclusivity, it is reasonable to claim that Nielsen had little choice but to respond with exclusive contract proposal of its own. If Nielsen had responded with non-exclusive contractual bids, then ooq outcome unfavourable to Nielsen would be for IRI to have secured some exclusive retail customers and for Nielsen to have secured some customen on a non-exclusive basis. These retail customen then would have been in a position to also sell their data to IRI giving IRI the opportunity to secure a national sample, sufficiently reliable to market a national scanning based market tracking service. Under this outcome, N~elsen could have secured some retail customers but found itself unrepresented in certain regions of the country. Furthermore, Nielsen would be in a weak position to strike a deal to secure IRI's exclusive data. To produce national data, N"telsm would have had to replace the missing data with data from other sources. If this were grossly inferior, Nielsen would have had to abandon its attempt to produce national marketing tracking data services. Of course, Nielsen could have developed a regional market tracking service.

13 2.4.3 In 1986, with the initiative of IRI, rights to acquire scanning data from all major retailers were up for bidding. The collective initiative of IRI with all major retail grocery chains was promoted by the Retail Council of Canada. For 1986, it is reasonable to claim that the dominant strategy for Nielsen was to respond by offering exclusive contracts of its own. The evidence is that, in 1986 in contrast to IRI's all~r-nothing bid, Nielsen's bids were nonetheless on an individual basis to each major retail grocery chain independent of the other chains. The end result of this initial game was that Nielsen was the successful bidder.

2.4.4 Subsequent bids for retail grocery chain contracts were different from the 1986 . period. As the contracts that were signed in 1986 did not all expire at the same moment in . · time, future contracts were negotiated between intermediaries such as Nielsen and retailers in a continuing Independent fashion but one that was now sequential in nature. Any potential entrant to the marketing service business in Canada who wished to bid for the right to assemble, process and sell scanner data could bid on each retailer contract as it came due. Any potential entrant who successfully secured a contract with exclusive rights to broker the scanning data of a specific retailer would be in a position to negotiate with other intermediaries over the excbanae of their data to facilitate a scanning based market tracking service.

1.4.S The original retail contracts have all exphed and, for most of the original retailers, these contracts have been renegotiated. The termination dates for the second round of contracts continues to reveal variation. For example, the second canada Safeway contract is

currently under negotiation while the second As well, some retailer contracts have options that permit the retailer to terminate the contract before the contract's official termination date Along the way, other retailers (for example: . suppliers of scanning data to Nielsen.

(b) prospective 2.4.6 While Canada provides one example of how the business of collecting and processing national scanner data might evolve, other potential arrangements are possibilities. For example, intermediaries and sellers of marketing services such as Nielsen could act as brokers, collecting and processing the data for retailers and manufacturers (together with selling other decision support services) with those manufacturers desiring to purchase key account data paying the retailer directly. A market with two major retailers might have two intermediaries assembling, processing and marketing scanning data on an exclusive basis for each. Under this arrangement each intermediary could provide key account data by respective retailer. Each manufacturer desiring a national tracking sample could enter into a separate contract with an intermediary (such as Nielsen or IRI) to assemble and collate the data bases to form a national sample. This illustrates another possibility for organizing market tracking services.

2.4. 7 Recently both . .md tequested that Nielsen submit contractual bids on both an exclusive and non-exclusive basis. This evidence supports the

14 contract does not expire until have become

15 claim that major grocery distributors in Canada are contract makers. In a world of sequential negotiation, each retail grocery chain selects that contract which is in the best interest of that chain.

(c) exclusivity 2.4.8 As contracts for scanning data continue to be negotiated and renewed upon their termination, for each retail contract, the process continues to be independent and sequential. In the face of retailer power to alter the fonn of the contract and to request bids from alternative suppliers, there is no ex ante guarantee that any exclusive contractual bid from Nielsen will be suc.cessful.

2.4.9 IRI had and continues to have the option to bid on any contract of Nielsen that expires. Based on its experience in the US, IRI is alteady present in market tracking service. IRI is also present in Canada marketing software services to retailers as well as to manufacturers. This is not an issue of a de noyo potential entrant. Furthermore, IRI's position for these expiring contracts does llSll mirror Nielsen's position in 1986. As I note, Nielsen's contractual bids were and are on an independent not an all-or-nothing basis. IRI could compete for the renewal business of the major retail grocery chains in Canada, on any basis it chooses.

2.4.10 For example, suppose that IRI also bid on the exclusive and a non-exclusive basis. One possible solution is that

contract on both an could

16 choose IRI as its exclusive agent. (When the contracts were simultaneously bid in 1986 with the all-or-nothing exclusiv:e initiative by IRI, division of the contracts across Nielsen and IRI did not appear to be a possibility.) This would leave IRI in a position to control as an exclusive agent an important data set from Western Canada.

2.4.11 There is evidence that the exclusionary and termination provisions vary across retailer contracts For example, the This could have broad application. This suggests that exclusionary and termination features in the contracts were not blanket provisions but were influenced through individual negotiation. This variability also provides some support for the claim that retailers do bargain over contractual provisions.

2.4.12 Ex-post, Nielsen's success at gaining exclusivity in its independent negotiations with the major retail chains in Canada at renewal time did offer the virtue of a complete national sample that facilitates a national market tracking service based on a complete sample from each retail repon of the country. 2 Similar to the hypothetical discussed above in 2.4.6, this outcome also satisfies the demand for national market tracking data. I can find no evidence that suggests that the ex-post exclusive arrangement currently in place in Canada is more or

2 The ease of assembling a representative national sample of data was recogni7.ed as an ex ante objective by IRI in its initiation of the exclusivity game across all major Canadian food retailers in 1986.

J.. 17

less competitive than the individual broker arrangements hypothesized above.

(d) rmancial inducements 2.4.13 With sparse and separated population centres, Canada has correspondingly sparse and separated retail markets. It is reasonable to claim as a consequence that even modest efficiencies from size in retailing (warehousing, distribution, and brand name capital) plus diseconomies associated with large distances will lead to a limited number of significant retail chains in Canada with geographical specialization.

2.4.14 With retail contracts for scanning data independently negotiated across the retail grocery chains, the expectation is that the payments to each retailer negotiating a contract with Nielsen will reflect at least the alternative opportunities available to that retailer to sell its data ~lsewhere (for example regional or key account) and be no greater than the value added by the inclusion of that retail chain's scanning data into an overall national market tracking product.

2.4. lS If acceu to national data provide higher quality and more reliable data, then a product with enbanad value will be worth more to users and should be associated with a higher payment to retail participants. To no one's surprise, larger and more powerful chains whose data is more critical to the end product are able to bargain for a larger proportion of the gains from trade associated with the product. This is consistent with competition. It suggests that larger retail organi:iations will command a larger price for their data and that

18 this price is limited by the value accorded the product in the larger market for marketing services. One option open to any retailer is to sell its scanning data to an intermediary who would use the data to provide either a regional market tracking service or to provide chain-specific key account data to manufacturers.

2.4.16 As I note above, exclusive contracts accepted by all major retailers have the ex-post advantage of national coverage. But, as I also note above, other contractual arrangements could exist that offer consistent national representation for sampling purposes.

2.4.17 Consider another hypothetical: If the existing contractual arrangements in the Canadian market were anticompetitive, then the food manufacturers would be faced with anticompetitive prices for market tracking products. Consistent with the Director's claim, suppose further that there are no substitute marketing service products available to manufacturers to discipline the sale of scanning based national market tracking data. Any alleged financial inducement offeml to retailers from a single intermediary would flow from the ensuing inflated and anticompetitive revenues from the sale of the product to manufacturers. Under this hypothetical, enhanced competition from other intermediaries should then reduce the financial inducements as the prices faced by manufacturers would be lower as would be the intermediaries' revenues. Is this is the expectation of IRI7 Based on the evidence from its promotional material to retailers, IRl's answer is no.

2.4.18 In its promotional material, IRI claims that IRl's entry into the Canadian market

19 would simultaneously both enhance competition and lead to larger payments to retailers. This claim runs counter to the anticompetitive hypothetical posed in 2.4.17 above.

2.5 Competitive Efl'ects (a) lenatb of contract 2.S. l There are a number of commercial facton that determine the length of the contract. For the retailer contracts at issue here, I am informed by Nielsen personnel that the pressure from retailers is for comparatively shorter contracts. The rationale is that shorter term contracts enhance flexibility for retailers to adapt to unfolding ~ents. For example, a retail chain that realimi an enhanced market share might argue that its scanning data are more valuable and the fees paid for the use of this data should increase. With exchange governed by the contracts currently in place, this would require a renegotiation of the existing contract. A shorter term contract would permit more frequent negotiation. Intermediaries such as Nielsen wish to have comparatively longer term contracts. The rationale is that securing retailers for a longer period permits the intermediary to plan its investments and product development with enhanced security. The ob~ed contract length is determined in the negotiation process between the retail grocery chain and the intermediary. Its length reflects these commercial factors. I could find no evidence of strategic manipulation of contract length by Nielsen to facilitate any anticompetitive objective.

20 (b) prices and senices in Canada 2.5.2 The evidence from Nielsen is that its real prices in Canada for its scanning based market tracking product not only have not risen over the period from 1986 to the present but have fallen slightly. Real prices remained constant in spite of the difficulties experienced by Nielsen in bringing on stream its scanning-based market tracking services. These difficulties resulted from the low and variable quality of raw data submitted to Nielsen by the retail grocery chains.

2.S.3 During this period, Nielsen maintained data collection from both its former data sources (consumer panels, store audit, and warehouse withdrawal) and the scanning based sample of retail grocery outlets. The evidence is that Nielsen's costs increased at the same time as it commenced significant payments to the retailers under its obligations in the retail contracts.

2.S.4 As the scanning based data improved, Nielsen petsonnel maintain that the quality of the market tracking services provided to both retailers and manufacturers improved. In sum, the period from 1986 to 1992 wu cbaracteriz.ed by constant or marginally declining real prices associated with a national market tracking product, a discrete improvement in the quality of the product as scanner based data became more reliable and useable, and increased costs to Nielsen during the transition phase because of the need to maintain the former data sources and collection until the quality of the scanning based data met minimum quality and regional representation standards.

21 (c) entry 2.5.5 Entry into marketi~g services was feasible during the period from 1986 to 1994. First a firm providing marketing services could obtain any required data input from its client whether this client was a retail grocery chain or a manufacturer. Entry into the data generation business using data provided by non-scanning sources of data was also feasible. Finally there were the critical points when retail contracts expired where entrants could bid against Nielsen on whatever terms they chose and the retail grocery chains requested. Of course, in the face of competition, there is no guarantee that a given entrant or entry strategy will be successful. A potential entrant into Canada such as IRI building on its US and worldwide base would appear to have a considerable advantage over a de poyo entrant. There is nothing to prevent IRI from bidding agaressively and sequentially for each retail contract in Canada as it terminated. As I point out above, given the nature of the market for retail groceries in Canada, successfully winning the contract for one retail chain would provide an entrant with something of value to trade with Nielsen to satisfy market demands for a national market tracking product. As an alternative, IRI could consider a toehold-entry strategy of building from a regional or key account to a national service.

22 3 Conclusiom 3. 1 In Canada in 1986, the contractual process for the sale of scanner data to data intermediaries was initiated by IRI's exclusive, all-or-nothing bids to major retail grocery chains.

3.2 This bid by IRI was unsuccessful. Nielsen successfully negotiated contracts with these chains on an chain-independent basis.

3.3 There are alternative sources of market tracking data available in Canada. r. 3.4 Major retail grocery chains in Canada and many of the manufacturers who use mark.et tracking services are large and capable of negotiating favourable terms in their contracts with suppliers of inputs such as Nielsen.

3.~ Since 1986, the contract negotiation process between the major retail grocery chains and Nielsen has been independent and sequential. This means that a firm such as IRI established in the US and other world markets could have chosen to bid on these contracts on any basis it saw fit, in accordance with each retailer's request.

3.6 I could find no evidence that Nielsen used financial inducements in an anticompetitive manner to induce the major retail grocery store chains to use Nielsen as their exclusive agent

for scanning data.

3. 7 I could find no evidence that the length of the contract with each of the major retail grocery chains does not reflect conventional commercial principles when parties negotiate a contract.

3. 8 The evidence is that during the period 1986 to the present the real price of the Nielsen market tracking service was constant or declined marginally and the quality of the product increased as, among other things, the scanning based data became more reliable and usable.

23

24 APPENDIX A CURRICULUM VITAE

May 1994 Home Adclrw: 83 Lonsdale Road Toronto, Ontario M4V 1W4 Telephone: (416) 923-9749

Offke Addnp: Institute for Policy Analysis Univenity of Toronto 140 St. George Street, Suite 700 Toronto, Ontario MSS lAl Telephone: (416) 978-6127 Fax: (416) 978-SS19

E-Mail: frankm@epas.utoronto.ca .• Citlpmblg: Canadian Presept Position: Acting Chair (1994/9S) and Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Univenity of Toronto (1969 to present)

Research Associate, Institute for Policy Analysis Univenity of Toronto (1969 to present)

Preyioqs Positfom: Visiting Research Fellow, Department of Political Economy, University College, University of London, 1976-77.

Professor of F.cooomics, Faculty of Management Studies, University of Toronto, 1970-82.

Senior Research Associate, Ontario Economic Council, 1978-79. Aslociate Chairman and DiMctor of Graduate Studies, Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 1978-83.

Visiting Scholar, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Spring Quarter, 1984.

Visiting Professor, Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, University of Chicago, Spring Qtwter, 198S.

25 EclucaUon: B.Com. University of Toronto 1965 Ph.D. Stanford University 1970

Fellowshjgs and Social Science and Humanities Research Council Otber Ronon: Research Fellowship (1994, 1991, 1989, 1987, 1986, 1985). Social Science and Humanities Research Council Leave Fellowship (1983-84).

Canadian Council Leave Fellowship (1976-77). Canada Council Doctoral Fellowship (1966-69). Woodrow Wilson Fellowship (1965). Associate Editor, International Journal of Industrial OrJaniUon (1982-1988).

Co-editor with J. Stiglitz, New Dcvekgnents in tbe Analysis of Market Sttuctures, 1985, Cambridge: MIT Preu.

Editorial Board, Economic IoQUiry (1987-present) Editorial Board, Jouma1 of lndJ•CW F&onomics (1990 - present) Editorial Board, Iourpal of E&onogjig of Business (1992 - present) Editorial Board, Mangerial and Decision F.conomics (1994 - present) Co-editor with M. Trebilcock and M. Walker, The I.aw and F..cooomics of Cogg!tition Policy, 1990, Vancouver: The Fraser Institute Other Actb""'' Program Committee, Conference on Industrial Organi1.ation, International Economics Association, 1982.

Program Committee, European Association for Research in Industrial Economics, 1983 - 91.

26 Publiqtiom: "A .Consumer Theory of Demand for the Media", Journal of Business, 45(2), April 1972: 212-224.

"A Note on the Price Effects of Market Power in the Canadian Newspaper Industry", Canadian Journal of Economics, 5(2), May 1972: 298-301.

"Metering Costs and Marginal Cost Pricing in Public Utilities", with G.D. Quirin, Bell Journal of F.conomics, 3(1), May 1972: 335-339. Cents and Nonsense;: The F.conomics of Canadian Policy Issues with J. Carr and J. McManus, Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1972, 124

pages.

"Price Effects of Market Power in the Canadian Newspaper Industry: Reply•, Canadian Journal of F.cooomics, 7(1), February '. 1974: 130-132. "Economies of Scale in Financial Institutions: A General Model Applied to Insurance• with P. Halpern, Journal of Monetary F.cooomics, 1(2), April 197S: 203-220.

"The Benefits and Costs of Rate of Return Regulation" with J. Callen and H. Mohring, American F.conomic Reyiew, 66(S), June 1976: 290-297.

"Economies of Scale in Financial Institutions: Reply" with P. Halpern, Journal of Monetary F.cooomics, 3, 1m: 121-131. "The Residential Demand for Electrical F.nergy and Natural Gas: A Model Estimated for Canada• with R. Hyndman and Y. Kotowitz in

W.T. Ziemba et al (eds.), Enm,y Polic;y Modellin1: United States and Canadjag Ell)Crlcnccs, Martinus Nijboff Press, 1980, pp.86-102. (Paper presented at the Canadian F.nergy Policy Modelling Conference,

Vancouver, 1978.)

F.cooomics of Fipl TADsfet Pricin1 in Multinational Corporations with G.D. Quirin, University of Toronto Press (Ontario Economic Council Research Studies), 1978, 208 pages.

"Some Issues on Public Advertising• with Y. Kotowitz, Jouma1 of Contemporary Busineu, 7(4), 1979: 123-124.

27 "Informative Advertising and Welfare" with Y. Kotowitz, American Economic Review, 69(3), June 1979: 284-294.

"Advertising, Consumer Information and Product Quality" with Y. Kotowitz, Bell Journal of Economics, 10(2), Fall 1979: 566-588. (Paper presented at the European Econometric Society Meetings, Geneva, 1978).

Information. Entry and Rgulation in Markets for Life Insurance, University of Toronto Press (Ontario Economic Council Research Studies), 1982, 117 pages.

"An Economic Theory of Union-Controlled Finns" with Y. Kotowitz, F&onomica, 49 (196), November 1982: 421-433. (Paper presented at the Canadian Economics Association Meetings, Quebec City, 1978).

"The Rationale for Government .Regulation of Quality"; "Policy Alternatives in Quality Regulation" with D. Dewees and '-M. Trebilcock, "Markets for Insurance: A Selective Survey of Economic Issues", in D. Dewees (ed.), The Replation of OJialib', Toronto: Butterwortbs 1983.

Replation of Canadian Markets for Life Insurance with R. Winter, Department of Consumer and Corporate Affairs, Government of Canada, 1983.

"Entry, Siz.e Distribution, Scale and Scope Economies in the Life Insurance Industry" with S. Kellner, Joumal of Busineu, 56(1), January 1983: 2S-44.

"Vertical lntepation by Contractual Restraints in Spatial Markets" with R. W'mter, Journal of Bnpncy, S6(4), October 1983: 497-S18. "The Incentives for Resale Price Maintenance" with R. Winter, Economic Inguity, 21(3), July 1983: 337-348. (Paper presented at the Western Economic Auociation Meetings, San Francisco, 1981).

"Information, Search and Price Variability of Individual Life Insurance Contracts•, Journal of lnduatria1 fmoomics, 32(2), December 1983: 131-148. (Paper presented a1 the Canadian Economics Association Meetings, Montreal, 1980).

28 "The Economics of Vertical Restraints in Distribution" with R. Winter in J. Stiglitz and G.F. Mathewson (eds.), New Develwments in the Analysis of Market Structure, 1986: MIT Press. (Paper presented at the IEA Conference, Ottawa, 1982) .

.. An Economic Theory of Vertical Restraints• with R. Winter, Rand Journal of Economics, lS(l), Spring 1984: 27-38. (Paper presented at the EARIE Conference, Louvain, 1982).

"The Economics of Life Insurance Regulation: Valuation Constraints• with R. Winter in J. Finsinger and M. Pauly (eds.), The F.cooomics of Insurance Rqulation, 1986, MacMillan and Company Limited. (Paper presented at IIM Conference on Regulation in Insurance Markets, Berlin, 1984).

"The Economics of Franchise Contracts• with R. Winter, Journal of Law and Economics, (3), October 198S: S03-S26. (Paper presented at the EARIE Conference, Fontainebleau, 1984). ·-Competition Polic;y and vertical Excbanp with Ralph Winter, University of Toronto Press, (Royal Commission on the Economic Union and Development Prospects for Canada), 198S, 119 pages.

•Advertising and Consumer Leaming• with Y. Kotowitz, in FTC Conference Volume, Consumer Prptectim F.conomics, 1986. (Paper presented at the FTC Conference on Advertising, Washington, 1984).

"Is Exclusive Dealing Anti-Competitive?• with R. Wmter, Amerigo Economic Rcyicw, 'n(S),December 1987: 10S7 - 1062. ·unlimited Liability u a Barrier to F.ntry• with Jack Carr, Journal of Political fqmmy, 96(4), August 1988: 766-784. •vertical Restraints and the Law: A Reply• with Ralph Winter, Rand.. Journal of Fa>nomics, 19(2), Summer 1988: 298 - 301. "Unlimited Liability and Free Banking in Scotland: A Note• with Jack Carr and S. Glied, Journal of F&onomic History, 49(4), 1989: 974-78. •nie Economic Effects of Automobile Dealer Regulation• with Ralph Winter, Ann•'m d'F.qmomic et de Stalistigµc, lS/16, Juillet-D6cembre 1989: 409 - 426.

"The Economics of Law Firms: A Study in the Legal Organization of the Firm• with Jack Carr, Journal of Law and F&onomics, 33(2),

1990: '3<J1 - 330.

"Reply to R. Gilson" with Jack Carr, Journal of Political F&onomy, 99(2) 1991: 426 - 428.

"Territorial Rights in Franchise Contracts• with Ralph Winter, (presented at the EARIE Conference, Budapest Hungary, 1989), F&onomic Inguiry, 32(2), 1994: 181 - 192.

Eosurin1 Failure with Jack Carr and Neil Quigley, 1994 Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.

"Stability in the Absence of Deposit Insurance: The Canadian Banking System 1890 - 1966• with Jack Carr and Neil Quigley, forthcoming Journal of Money. Creclit and Bankin1. Papen Vnder geyiew: "Tying As a Response to Demand Uncertainty• with Ralph Winter (presented at the EARIE Conference, Lisbon Portugal 1990).

"The Political Economy of Deposit Insurance• with Jack Carr and Neil Quigley.

"Buyer Groups: Towards a Theory of Managed Competition• with Ralph W'mter (presented at the EARIE Conference Tel Aviv Israel 1993).

"Rent capture in canadian Medical care• with Jack Carr (presented at the EARIB Conference, Tel Aviv Israel 1993). •stability in the Absence of Deposit Insurance: The Canadian Banking System 1890 - 1966• with Jack Carr and Neil Quigley.

Work In Pmcr•: •Buying Groups and Strategic Behavior,• with Ralph W'mter. "Partnership Dissolution,• with Aloysius Siow.

29

30 Expert Eridence: I was the economic expert for the Pharmacy Association of Nova Scotia (and the other accused) in November 1992 - Queen V. Nova Scotia Pharmaceutical Society et al.

I was the economic expert for Aerospatiale/ Alenia in their bid to acquire the assets of the deHavilland Division of the Boeing Corporation. In 1991, I testified before the European Economic Commission in a hearin& on this matter.

I was the economic expert for the NutraSweet Company in hearinas before the Competition Tribunal in 1990.

I was the economic expert for the Epson Company in 1987 durin& the sentencing phase of

its trial over charges on resale price maintenance.

 Vous allez être redirigé vers la version la plus récente de la loi, qui peut ne pas être la version considérée au moment où le jugement a été rendu.